Agrigyan

Write us

info@agrigyan.com

+91 9999052385

Request a call back

The Devil Lies in the Detail !

Recuperating from a recurrent fever over the last few days was a blessing in disguise!

As I  mulled over the Delhi Agricultural Produce  Marketing (Regulation ) Act , and the proposed changes  as per the Model Act of Government of India  ,  I realized that the  devil was in the fine print.  While the intent of  the rechristened Act , Delhi Agriculture Produce Marketing (Regulation) (Development ) Act   was stated ‘to provide  for the better regulation of marketing of agricultural produce, and the establishment of markets for  agricultural produce in the  National Capital Territory of Delhi, and for matters  therewith, or incidental thereto’ , the context, the  definitions  and the Rules  framed, or authorized under the Act diffuse  the intent  of the legislation. Even though the proposed amendment makes a distinction between Regulation and Development, it does not separate the regulatory regime from the development role: more importantly, it allows the existing players to keep out potential competition by recourse to ‘Rules’, which are never debated in the Assembly.

The problem starts with an understanding of the agricultural markets of Delhi. Delhi is not a ‘market’ where ‘agriculturists’ of Delhi bring their primary produce for sale. It is a market of the traders, by the traders and for the traders. While the Act classifies them as brokers, buyers and commission agents, in essence, they perform the function of aggregating agricultural produce from wherever they can, and selling  to wholesalers and retailers in Delhi and the surrounding areas.  Most agricultural produce sold in the markets of Delhi comes from a very extensive hinterland (J&K, HP, Uttarakhand, Punjab, Haryana, UP, Rajasthan, Gujarat and Maharashtra), but not limited to these states. Many of the leading   fruit traders in Azadpur Mandi are now importing fruits from Afghanistan, Pakistan, China, US, Australia. New Zealand and Thailand. By Delhi government’s own admission, by the end of this  decade, all of Delhi’s area will be classified as urban .  Except for  the boutique farmhouses of  the rich and famous, there will  be no real ‘farmers’  in Delhi !

As such, Delhi’s agricultural markets have to protect the interest of the 18 million consumers, and the large number of institutional buyers- from hotels, hostels and hospitals and organizations like railways and defence. Thus while the volume and value of agricultural produce has increased manifold, the number of intermediaries has been frozen because of Rule 17 (f) which stipulates that permission for grant of new license can be refused if: “the person applying for license has no premises to carry on business or marketing of agricultural produce”. The premises in the existing  markets/sub –markets /market yards of  Delhi  have already been allotted, and there is no  realistic possibility of  additional premises being built  in these markets – thereby sealing the monopoly of the existing licensees. In effect, if a RWA, or JNU or Big Bazaar, or even the Kendriya Bhandar (central government employees co-operative society) wishes to engage directly with the apple growers co-operatives of HP or J&K for purchase of their produce for their own members, they are not entitled to do so legally. They will have to do so through an intermediary in the Azadpur market. Now that the horticulture train has started  moving bananas  from Raver in Maharashtra  to Azadpur  rail terminal – the issue  is that  business can be transacted only by the  licensed traders, thereby  distorting the price discovery mechanism in a manner which is unfavourabe to the primary producer.

What can be done?
First the roles of the government, the Board and the market committees constituted under the Board must be clearly defined.  Government has to provide an enabling policy environment and look at the eco-system in which the Act has to operate.  It is for the government to identify the new stakeholders, (RWAs, institutional buyers, organized retailers) and engage in discussions with them on the broad contours of the proposed legislation. The Board has to regulate and  register (and in the interim, grant license), and the markets constituted under the Board ,viz Azadpur, Okhla, Mehraulli, Ghazipur Tikri etc. have to  ensure that the actual trade is carried out in a transparent manner, and provide the necessary infrastructure  :  electronic auction platforms, logistics, warehousing, CA storage, financial services and support services for  the large number of people engaged in the transactions – drivers, weigh men, loaders, packers, traders, agriculturists, officials ,market analysts and all those engaged in the ecosystem. Second, the licensing function has to be taken out of the ambit of the market committees and replaced with provisions of registration by the Board.

This would also render the extant classification of traders into buyers, brokers and commission agents redundant.  Anyone who wants to trade in agricultural commodities should be encouraged to do so on the payment of  a  fixed( nominal) registration fee,(to be paid to the Board)   and a transaction fee based on the value of the  trade (to the market committee). This will also ensure the financial viability of the market committees, besides ensuring continuous improvement and upgrading of infrastructure mentioned in the preceding paragraph.

Third, the physical architecture of the market with individual shops and auction platforms should be replaced with trading platforms with e-auction facilities.  Existing traders, as well as commodity and spot exchanges could also be encouraged to establish such platforms where agricultural goods could be displayed. All new markets that come up in Delhi should take the precaution of designing the market in a manner which encourages price discovery through greater participation, rather than retain the monopoly of the existing players.